Phone: (585) 412-6895 Email
Address: 165 Saxton Lane, Canandaigua, NY 14424, USA
By Jeff Adams, May 11, 2016
As it appears that Hillary Clinton and Donald Trump will be the party nominees for the November 2016 Presidential Election, it is time to make a more detailed comparison of their policies. In particular, this article analyzes the various points in their health care proposals. At the time of writing this paper, there are slightly less than six months remaining until the election. Candidates may alter their proposals slightly between now and the election, but chances are that they will not change significantly.
The following is a brief discussion of our health care system followed by a point by point discussion of the proposals of the two candidates:
Background
An increasing number of people have the opinion that the issues facing our health care system and the resulting effects of these issues on the United States are the biggest problem facing this country today. One of the major reasons for these concerns is that health care costs are eating up a much larger portion of the Federal Budget, causing cutbacks on spending for discretionary items such as defense, scientific and biomedical research, NASA, federal law enforcement, and social programs. Not only do restrictions on spending for defense lessen our national security, less discretionary spending by the Federal government means a reduction in money flowing to state and local governments, causing fiscal issues for these governments. In 1990, health care represented 12.5% of Federal expenditures and rose steadily to 26.4% in 2014. As a result of this increase, discretionary spending decreased from 38.6% of total Federal expenditures in 1990 to 31.3% in 2014. A continuation of this trend would cause additional cuts in discretionary spending and stress on the security and infrastructure of the United States.
The Federal Budget is not the only place where rapid growth in health care costs is causing major problems. In the United States as a whole, health care represented 12.1% of the Gross Domestic Product (“GDP”) in 1990 and grew steadily to 17.5% of GDP in 2014. In the early 1990s, economists suggested that health care would not increase to over 20% of GDP as this would cause substantial economic issues for the country, yet we are on the brink of that occurring. Employers fund a substantial portion of the cost of health care, making it easier for employees to obtain affordable coverage. Since the 1990s, however, employers have been choosing to drop coverage for their employers due to large cost increases, and even employers who maintain coverage cover a smaller proportion of the health care cost, thus increasing the uninsured rate. Even employees who are able to retain coverage find that the increased out-of-pocket amounts that they must pay are putting a strain on their economic well-being.
The Affordable Care Act, or ObamaCare, has made it possible for millions of people to obtain affordable health care through premium subsidies and benefit subsidies, but tens of millions still remain without coverage. Increases in the cost of health care slowed slightly after the passage of ObamaCare, but many analysts are saying that the growth in health care costs is starting to increase again. The 17.5% of GDP that the United States spent on health care is substantially more than the percent spent by any other industrialized country, yet the United States ranks average in quality of care surveys for these same countries. Much of the cost issue is due to fraud, waste, and abuse. Studies have been done since the 1990s, indicating that 25% of all health care costs are fraud, waste, and abuse. This has been increasing over the years, and, for the first time, I have seen reports that fraud, waste, and abuse have risen to between 33% and 50% of all health care costs (Aetna posted this on its website).
Candidate Health Proposals
Listed below are the proposed health care plans for the two presumptive Presidential candidates, along with comments and analysis:
Donald Trump – Republican
The Donald Trump health care plan was taken from his web site:
Here are the components of his plan and accompanying comments:
1. Completely repeal Obamacare. Our elected representatives must eliminate the individual mandate. No person should be required to buy insurance unless he or she wants to.
Analysis: The Republicans have been trying to repeal ObamaCare since the day it was first passed. Although part of the push to repeal is simply party politics, there is the large government versus small government perspectives of the two parties at odds again. The Republicans see ObamaCare as an extension of the massive government Medicare and Medicaid programs that are already draining the government’s coffers, while the Democrats see ObamaCare as an opportunity to help millions of Americans obtain health insurance and find ways to slow the growth in health care costs.
The individual mandate was put into ObamaCare for a couple of reasons. The first is to help alleviate the issue of bad debt and charity, where uninsured or underinsured persons obtain services from providers but then cannot pay for the services. A substantial portion of these charges is currently charged back to the payors (insurance carriers, health insurance funds, etc.) through government fees or higher provider payments and passed on in the form of higher premiums. The individual mandate would cause fewer people to be uninsured, resulting in less bad debt and charity claims and lower premium rates for the insured. The other reason for the mandate is to encourage younger, healthier individuals to obtain coverage, thus lowering overall premiums. Opponents say that the government should not have the authority to force individuals to purchase health insurance. Proponents claim that persons with insurance should not be forced to subsidize those who do not purchase insurance.
There is probably no correct answer as to whether to repeal ObamaCare or not, but any proposal to repeal ObamaCare must contain components that will reduce the issues of the large number of uninsured individuals and rapidly rising health care costs.
2. Modify existing law that inhibits the sale of health insurance across state lines. As long as the plan purchased complies with state requirements, any vendor ought to be able to offer insurance in any state. By allowing full competition in this market, insurance costs will go down, and consumer satisfaction will go up.
Analysis: This is a bad idea. The concept of allowing insurers to sell across state lines is very common in Republican health care proposals. The objective is to avoid state mandates of the states in which the policies are being sold. This would be accomplished by having an insurer “headquartered” in a state with minimal mandates and then having this insurer sell policies in states with substantial mandates. States have very different mandated benefits or rating requirements. Allowing insurers to sell policies across the nation that only have the mandates of the regulations of the states with the least regulation would cause many issues. One issue is that enrollees purchasing coverage would have no security as to what is covered in the benefits package that they purchase. States put in mandated benefits such as maternity, cancer coverage, mental and nervous, women’s health benefits, etc., because individuals were purchasing policies and then, after having payment denied for services, realizing that they had no coverage for the specific services that they had performed on them or that there was a lifetime or annual maximum in benefit payments that had been exceeded, resulting in large out-of-pocket expenses for the policyholder, possible financial issues, and even bankruptcy.
Allowing cross-state sale of health care would also allow insurers to avoid community-rate requirements in many states. Community rates are rates based on the number of claims that an entire pool of beneficiaries has and does not allow rates for a group within the pool to be based on claims for only those people in the group being rated. The idea of community-rating is to require rates for good claims experience to be the same as rates for groups with bad claims experience, thus stabilizing rates and rate increases over time. Elimination of this community-rated requirement would not actually lower overall rates; it would allow groups with better-than-average experience in a given year to have lower rates but would then require groups with worse than average experience in a given year to have higher rates. Some of the groups that would get higher rate increases for several could eliminate coverage because the rates could become unaffordable.
3. Allow individuals to fully deduct health insurance premium payments from their tax returns under the current tax system. Businesses are allowed to take these deductions, so why wouldn’t Congress allow individuals the same exemptions? As we allow the free market to provide insurance coverage opportunities to companies and individuals, we must also make sure that no one slips through the cracks simply because they cannot afford insurance. We must review basic options for Medicaid and work with states to ensure that those who want healthcare coverage can have it.
Analysis: Allowing individuals to deduct health insurance premiums for income tax purposes is a good proposal, although it does not help with the underlying issues within our health care system. It is not clear whether the medical premium deduction would be subject to the same 10% of adjusted gross income threshold that other medical expenses are. Since the individual may also receive significant assistance from their employer or government subsidies, the resulting deductible premium amount would theoretically be the individual’s contribution to getting coverage and not the actual total premium amount. For example, if Joe’s company ABC Corporation, purchased coverage from XYZ Insurer for $1,000 a month or $12,000 a year and Joe had to contribute $200 a month or $2,400 a year to get this coverage, then only the $2,400 would be deductible and possibly only to the extent that the contributions plus all other deductible medical expenses exceeded 10% of adjusted gross premiums. Also, there is the possibility that the individual would not be able to deduct this even if medical expenses plus medical premium exceeded 10% of adjusted gross income if total deductions (charitable deductions, interest, etc.) did not exceed the standard deductible amount. If medical expenses exceeded 10% of Adjusted Gross Income and the individual itemized deductions, they would only receive partial recovery for the health expenses they had to pay. For example, if the individual were in the 15% tax bracket and could deduct $1,000 in medical premiums, the savings would be $150 of the $1,000 in expenses.
4. Allow individuals to use Health Savings Accounts (HSAs). Contributions into HSAs should be tax-free and should be allowed to accumulate. These accounts would become part of the estate of the individual and could be passed on to heirs without fear of any death penalty. These plans should be particularly attractive to young people who are healthy and can afford high-deductible insurance plans. These funds can be used by any member of a family without penalty. The flexibility and security provided by HSAs will be of great benefit to all who participate.
Analysis: This is probably a good idea and should be studied, but, again, does little to help issues facing our health care system. The suggested proposal expands current HSA regulation and would allow individuals to put money away tax-free and use it at any time when out-of-pocket health care costs are incurred. Care would need to be taken in passing this legislation that loopholes would not be opened that would allow individuals to put money into these HSAs for the purpose of avoiding taxes and passing the HSA monies on to heirs who would also not have to pay taxes on the money.
5. Require price transparency from all healthcare providers, especially doctors and healthcare organizations like clinics and hospitals. Individuals should be able to shop to find the best prices for procedures, exams, or any other medical-related procedure.
Analysis: The idea is a good one and should be studied and then implemented in some proposal that would make it an effective tool for consumers. The idea of transparency is simple, allowing patients to see prices of services or drugs before they purchase them, but implementation is complicated.
One reason for the complexity of implementing a transparency proposal is that not only do payors (insurance companies, HMOs, government programs, self-funded plans, etc.) have different payments for the same procedures for the same provider. Some payors even have multiple arrangements whereby the payor pays a given provider different amounts depending on the benefit plan in which the patient is enrolled. For example, Insurer ABC may pay Doctor XYZ $75 for a given procedure under its basic plan but only pay that same doctor $65 under its limited network plan that has a much smaller network of physicians. Another complicating factor is that rebates may be offered, as is done with many prescription drugs in the form of coupons that make the price calculation more complex. The “price” of a drug may be $100, but the patient may receive a coupon from the pharmaceutical manufacturer for $10 through the mail, thus reducing the net cost. Eventually, there will probably be automated systems to be able to handle all of these complexities, but a full system still needs to be developed.
Another complicating factor is that individuals have different benefit. If Joe Smith and Marty Jones have Insurer ABC and the same $75 procedure performed by Doctor XYZ, Joe Smith may have a $10 copay and have to pay only $10 for that procedure while Marty Jones might have a $1,000 deductible and have to pay the entire $75. Not only does this complicate an automated transparency system, but there is also no incentive for Joe Smith to switch to Doctor LMN, who gets paid only $20 for the procedure and has the same, or better, quality of care. This is because the cost to Joe Smith would be only $10 no matter which doctor he chose. Having a system whereby Joe Smith was given an incentive to switch to a lower-cost doctor would lower health care costs. Allowing Joe Smith to sit down with his primary care physician, for example, and look at the costs of the different treatment, provider quality of care scores, and comparative effectiveness analysis for the various treatments available would be extremely useful in lowering cost, raising quality of care, and increasing quality of life.
This is a long way of saying that the transparency is a good start, but there must be additional components put into any transparency proposal to make it effective.
6. Block-grant Medicaid to the states. Nearly every state already offers benefits beyond what is required in the current Medicaid structure. The state governments know their people best and can manage the administration of Medicaid far better without federal overhead. States will have the incentives to seek out and eliminate fraud, waste, and abuse to preserve our precious resources.
Analysis: This is probably a good idea, for the reasons stated. The only downside is that it might make it slightly easier for the Federal government to substantially limit Medicaid payments to the states since it would no longer be a “Federal” program. This same negative is actually a positive in the sense that the Federal government would be more able to control Medicaid spending in the Federal Budget.
7. Remove barriers to entry into free markets for drug providers that offer safe, reliable, and cheaper products. Congress will need the courage to step away from the special interests and do what is right for America. Though the pharmaceutical industry is in the private sector, drug companies provide a public service. Allowing consumers access to imported, safe, and dependable drugs from overseas will bring more options to consumers.
Analysis: This may be a viable option if there was testing done on imported drugs. Allowing individuals to get drugs from any country is a bad idea as many countries do not have regulations that require drugs to be tested to make sure they are safe and that they actually work.
Pharmaceutical manufacturers may sell drugs for a much higher price in the United States than they do in other countries, but there are other ways to approach this problem than to have loose restrictions on imported drugs. As long as the new regulation ensures proper testing of the imported drugs, this is a viable option that would lower cost and not lower quality of care.
The following web site has a general overview of Hillary Clinton’s health care plan:
The general components it lists are as follows:
1. Defend the Affordable Care Act and build on it to slow the growth of out-of-pocket costs.
Analysis: As stated earlier, there is no correct answer as to whether to repeal or not repeal ObamaCare. Repealing it and submitting a proposal that keeps the progress we have made under ObamaCare
(such as a lower number of uninsured individuals and a slowing of the growth rate in health care costs) would be difficult. It is probably safer to retain ObamaCare and modify it to make it more effective by adding components that slow the growth in cost while increasing quality of care.
This proposal mentions lowering the growth in out-of-pocket expenses. The best way to do this is to slow the overall growth in health care expenses. Some of the more detailed proposals tend to concentrate more on changing benefits so that the patient would pay less of the claims, but that would mean premiums would increase. The premium increase would be paid by a combination of the employer or plan sponsor and the patient.
2. Crack down on rising prescription drug prices and hold drug companies accountable so they get ahead by investing in research, not jacking up costs.
Analysis: I am not really sure that I can improve on this proposal. There is not a lot of detail in it, but the idea is a very good idea.
3. Protect women’s access to reproductive health care, including contraception and safe, legal abortion.
Analysis: The comment on access to contraceptives may be in response to Donald Trump’s proposal for cross-state sale of health care, which would probably substantially lessen the access to contraceptives as many states now mandate contraceptive coverage, and the Trump proposal would allow payors to virtually eliminate most mandates.
Additionally, Hillary announced this week that she would support a public option that would allow individuals under age 65 and not disabled to buy into Medicare under certain circumstances. It is not clear what these circumstances are and how much these individuals would have to pay for this coverage. Part A premiums for those who currently buy into Medicare Part A is $411 per month. Part B premiums for persons buying into Part B can be as low as $104.90. Generally, the target population that has been discussed in the past for allowing Medicare buy-in are persons close to Medicare eligibility age, such as those age 55 to 64. This public option would give these older adults, who are currently not eligible for Medicare, a less expensive option than would otherwise be available, but if it is decided that the premiums will be subsidized, it will drive up both Medicare expenditures and the Federal Budget deficit even higher.
The section below was taken from a previous article I had written in November 2015 when Hillary first released a detailed health care plan. It contains more details than (but is consistent with) the list above, so it is included below along with my comments written in that article:
1. Hillary’s plan would modify and add on to Obamacare, not repeal it.
Given the alternative proposals currently being presented by presidential candidates, modifying Obamacare seems to make more sense than repealing it and starting from scratch. The key point is that Obamacare must be modified as it has many issues but is still better than the alternatives. Obamacare gives coverage to millions who were previously uninsured. It also has components that may help reduce costs of health care and increase quality of care, but the effectiveness of these components will only be determined over time. One huge weakness of Obamacare is that the cost management components do not do nearly enough to control future increases in health care costs, arguably the biggest problem facing the United States today as funding for defense, infrastructure, education, and other important programs are redirected to cover health care costs. Increasing health care costs will also substantially increase the number of uninsured people in the United States as coverage becomes unaffordable for employers, individuals, Medicare enrollees, and even those with subsidies through the health insurance exchanges. Not repealing Obamacare may be a good thing as long as substantial additional measures are taken to increase quality of care and efficiency in our health care system.
2. The first three sick visits a year would not be subject to the deductible.
This seems like a reasonable approach as it allows individuals to see a doctor if they are sick without having to worry about paying for the visit if the individual has a large deductible. Although it would increase health care costs, it would also help improve the individual’s health status. The three visit limit before copays and deductibles apply would help control the cost of excessive doctor visits. Just a note though that the reason why deductibles are so large is that health care costs have been out of control for decades, and employers cannot afford the better benefit plans that they used to have for their employees in the past. Hillary’s plan does little to help rein in high health care trends.
3. Tax credits up to $2,500 individual and $5,000 family would be given if out-of-pocket health care costs exceeded 5% of income.
This is another reasonable approach to offset the cost of health care expenses. Currently, medical expenses exceeding 10% of income are deductible if the individual is itemizing deductions. The tax credit would allow a tax credit for even those who do not itemize deductions.
4. The ability to strengthen or modify “unreasonable” rate increases will be strengthened.
I have mixed feelings about this approach, but if used correctly, it can slow the growth in health care costs slightly. In today’s environment, an “unreasonable” rate increase is defined as a rate increase that exceeds 10% in a given year. Keep in mind that normal claims cost trends are 10% and higher for many benefits. This means that insurers may need to have rates approved if they are seeking rate increases that only cover normal trend increases. It is probably a good thing to have somebody looking over the shoulder of the insurance companies and making sure rate calculations are correct and assumptions are reasonable.
The major problem with the strengthened review approach is that under this type of rate review, the rate review authority often arbitrarily cuts back on rate increases, possibly due to political reasons or in the hopes that the insurance company can cut its costs. However, insurance companies use over 80% of the premium dollars to cover claims payments to hospitals, doctors, pharmaceuticals, and other health care vendors. Insurance companies have limited ability to negotiate fee payment schedules with these health care providers and virtually no negotiation leverage with pharmaceutical manufacturers, who can set prescription drug prices at a level of their own choosing. Health insurers can also try to control costs through reduction in the 30% of all health care costs that are fraud, waste, and abuse, but this is extremely difficult to do and generally met with cries of “rationing health care” and other arguments that we saw when HMOs became prevalent in the 1980s.
We probably need rate review for large rate increases, but there needs to be checks and balances so that we do not see a significant number of bankruptcies in health insurers as we sometimes see in states where rate review gets political.
5. Pharmaceutical manufacturers would not be able to deduct “marketing” expenses as a business expense.
On the surface, this might sound like a good idea, but its impact would only be higher health care premiums as pharmaceutical manufacturers would just raise the price of their drugs to cover the lost deductions. If there were even limited restrictions on drug prices, then eliminating the deduction for marketing expenses might have an impact but the reality is that it would not change the pharmaceutical manufacturers’ behavior, just increase drug prices. There needs to be some mechanism put in place to restrict the huge increases in prescription drug prices.
6. A minimum amount of money would be required to be spent by drug manufacturers on research and development.
I cannot really comment on this as I do not know the details of the plan. I think requiring a certain percentage of revenue on drug research and development is a good idea. Only requiring a set dollar amount would do little good as it would be a hardship for small pharmaceutical manufacturers and not impact large pharmaceutical manufacturers. A combination of minimum dollar and minimum percentage of revenue is also possible.
7. Prescription drug out-of-pocket maximums would be limited to $3,000 a year.
This would have a somewhat minimal impact and ignores the major problem in health care costs. Obamacare already has a total out-of-pocket maximum of $6,500, so if a person in a plan with this $6,500 maximum allowed out-of-pocket had non-drug out-of-pocket expenses of $3,500, then this proposal would have zero cost anyway. In reality, most plans have maximum out-of-pockets less than $6,500. This maximum drug out-of-pocket would only assist those with out-of-pocket drug expenses over $3,000 but who had limited other medical expenses, which is not a large number of people. This idea would increase premiums very slightly overall.
This idea also does nothing to help control the total cost of prescription drugs. Health care is arguably the fastest growing sector of our economy and has been so for decades. Prescription drugs are one of the fastest-growing components in health care and have been so for decades despite a slowdown in drug costs from around 2005 through 2014. Reducing out-of-pocket drug costs with no other changes would actually increase health care trends and compound the drug cost problem.
8. The sales exclusivity period for biotech drugs would be reduced from twelve years to seven years.
This is a reasonable step in order to cut prices on a few particular drugs, but its impact overall would not be substantial. Currently, pharmaceutical manufacturers have few restrictions on the prices that they can charge for their drugs, so reducing the sales exclusivity period may decrease costs only for those drugs that have been around for eight to twelve years if the manufacturer does not push through a “new-and-improved” drug to replace the drug whose sales exclusivity period is expiring. Pharmaceutical manufacturers will more quickly replace drugs whose sales exclusivity period is ending and pull the old drug off the market, leaving the new drug in an environment with no competition. Again, the key here is that there are no restrictions on how much pharmacy manufacturers can charge for their drug products, so the issue of costs during the sales exclusivity period is a subset of the overall problem of absolutely no controls over prescription drug prices.
9. Medicare would be given the ability of negotiating drug prices with pharmaceuticals.
Medicare should be given the ability to negotiate drug prices. It would have some, but not a lot, of leverage in negotiations with the pharmaceutical manufacturers. Some type of price restraint on drug prices is imperative. Additionally, these negotiated drug prices would serve as a guide for non-Medicare plans as to what drug prices may be reasonable.
Summary
The proposals above have significantly different approaches to health care reform. The voter should judge these proposals based on long-term effects on the growth of health care costs, increase in quality of care, and the resulting number of uninsured individuals. Unfortunately, partisan politics means that many Democrats will support Hillary’s plan solely because she is a Democrat, and many Republicans will support Donald Trump’s plan solely because he is Republican.
Another difficulty with the evaluation of health care reform proposals is that health care represented 17.5% of our economy in 2014 and is increasing steadily each year. That means that any significant proposal may impact that 17.5% of the economy, and any change may be resisted by individuals working in the health care sector or who have family working in the health care sector. Thus, emotions tend to run high when such proposals are discussed. For example, a proposal that is made to reduce health care cost increases might be termed a “job-killer.” Although it can be argued that this term is accurate, another way to look at it is that the increase in the number of jobs in health care would be slowed.
As an example of differences in perceptions making change difficult, I heard a presentation on the Internet that was done by the head of a medical center. He was very proud that he had helped the medical center increase its revenues significantly over the past couple of years, saying that the medical center would grow 20% in the next couple of years and that would be good for the community. To a health actuary’s ear, that sounded like “Our medical center managed to get substantially more payments out of the insurance carriers, HMOs, and government programs, and we expect to get 20% more out of them in the next couple of years, exacerbating our health care crisis.” In its defense, this medical center did implement a couple of programs that were designed to reduce costs while maintaining quality of care. This does point out the complexities of medical reform, though, as the employees of this medical center would be among the first to react emotionally to health care reforms as it would be a threat to job security, income, and financial security for their families.
In the opinion of a growing number of people, if left unabated, our health care system will get so large that it will cause a major crisis in the United States within the next 15 years, including possibly the elimination of Medicare for middle-income Americans. If we wait until that happens, then we will need to do a complete overhaul of our health care system at that time, which would mean the possible loss of millions of jobs. The alternative is to make incremental changes now that slow the growth of health care, allowing our economy to continue to expand.
General articles regarding health care reform are posted below in order from most recent to earliest posting date:
By Jeff Adams, September 16, 2013
The Affordable Care Act (“ACA”) legislated the establishment of health care Exchanges that would begin offering coverage to Individuals and Small Groups beginning on January 1, 2014, with open enrollment beginning on October 1, 2014. The following narrative describes some of the decisions and decision-processes that an Individual needs to make to determine what plan, if any, the Individual will purchase from the Exchange. I am an actuary, not an Exchange Navigator, so take this narrative in the spirit intended. It is generally good to get different perspectives on issues before deciding what to do. I hope the following is some assistance to those who are considering purchasing coverage on an Exchange. You may wish to consider meeting with a Navigator to discuss the details of your situation, as these Exchange Navigators are professionals designated to assist Individuals looking for Exchange health care coverage.
Exchanges are offered in each state, although an Exchange may be multi-state. Additional information may be obtained by visiting the Exchange’s website. Two of these websites are listed below:
New York Exchange Web Site
http://www.nystateofhealth.ny.gov/
California Health Insurance Exchange Web Site
http://www.healthexchange.ca.gov/Pages/Default.aspx
You should be able to find the web site for your state by doing a search for your state name and “health insurance exchange” or “health care exchange.”
Deciding Whether to Purchase Health Care Coverage from an Exchange?
For individuals and families who are eligible for coverage from the Individual Exchanges due to their inability to obtain affordable coverage (defined as health insurance coverage that costs 9.5% of income or less), deciding whether to purchase coverage can be difficult. Three factors that will greatly influence the decision are:
The risk tolerance of an individual or family is also extremely important. Given identical answers to 1, 2, and 3 above, two individuals may choose different options depending on each individual’s risk tolerance. An individual who is less risk-tolerant is more likely to pay insurance premiums in exchange for the safety net of coverage.
Penalty for Having No Health Coverage
In an effort to encourage individuals to buy health insurance coverage and in conjunction with the creation of Health Insurance Exchanges from which more affordable coverage may be purchased, ACA imposed penalties on individuals who do not have health insurance coverage in 2014. In 2014 this penalty was $95 per member, increasing to $325 per member in 2015, $695 per member in 2016, then increased by inflation each year thereafter. In the rare event that the average premium is less than the calculated per member penalty, the penalty is reduced to the premium amount.
The impact of this penalty is unknown, but a congressional budget analysis estimates that six million individuals will pay this penalty rather than purchase health insurance. Currently, it is estimated that over 50 million Americans are uninsured. The penalties, expansion of Medicaid in some states, and the income-based Premium Tax Subsidies for many purchasing insurance on the Exchanges will lower the uninsured rate.
Premium Tax Subsidy
The Premium Tax Subsidy is a subsidy given to households whose income is 100% to 400% of the Federal Poverty Level and who are eligible to purchase health insurance coverage from the Exchange. The 2013 Federal Poverty Level (“FPL”) is $11,490 for the head of the household and an additional $4,020 for each additional member of the household. Thus, the FPL for a family of four is $11,490 + 3 x $4,020 or $23,550 and a family of four with income between $23,550 and (400% x $23,550 =) $94,200 who are eligible for coverage on the Exchange may get subsidies.
The level of the subsidy varies by income as a percent of FPL. Eligible households with income at 100% of FPL ($23,550 for a family of four) and who do not have Medicaid will pay 2% of annual income for benchmark plan coverage. Households with income at 400% of FPL ($94,200 for a family of four) will pay 9.5% of income for Benchmark plan coverage. The Benchmark plan has a special meaning here: it is the second-least-expensive Silver plan available in the Exchange. A silver plan is a plan for which an insurer pays roughly 70% of allowable health care costs. An example of a Silver plan might be a $3,000 deductible plan where the member pays 20% of allowed charges above the deductible until the out-of-pocket maximum of $5,000 is reached, after which the member has no additional copayments.
As an example, assume that a family of four has a household income of $47,000 or roughly 200% of FPL. According to ACA, a household with income at 200% of FPL would have to pay approximately 6.3% of income, or 0.063 x $47,000 = $2,961 for Benchmark Silver coverage per year. If the actual Benchmark Silver plan premium family rate is $12,000 per year then the subsidy is $12,000 – $2,961 = $9,039. The household could use this subsidy against a plan of its choice. If the least-expensive Silver plan premium were $11,000, then this household would have to pay $11,000 – $9,039 = $1,961 for that benefit plan.
Cost-Sharing Reductions
Individuals and families with household income between 100% and 250% of FPL also are eligible for additional benefits. Households with income between 200% and 250% of FPL can get increased benefits, which are 73% of costs instead of the Silver Benchmark 70%. Households with income from 150% to 200% of FPL get benefits that are 87% of total allowed claims. Households with incomes between 100% and 150% of FPL can get benefits that are approximately 94% of the total allowed.
Cost of Coverage Versus the Cost of No Coverage
The decision of whether to purchase coverage from an Individual Exchange or to pay the penalty and take no coverage is dependent on the costs of those two options along with the amount of risk that the individual or household is willing to take.
For individuals or households with income in excess of 400% of FPL, there are no Premium Tax Subsidies to assist with premium payment or Cost-Share Reductions that would increase benefits by decreasing member copayments. The cost of having no coverage for this individual or household is the sum of the penalties for all members that choose not to have coverage plus the entire amount of all health care services that the individual or household incurs. The cost associated with choosing to purchase coverage would be the premium for the plan plus the deductibles, copays, coinsurance, and other out-of-pocket payments required by the plan. The potential policyholder would have to decide whether to buy the security of a policy or take the risk of having to pay large amounts in claims.
For individuals or households with incomes between 250% and 400% of FPL, the cost of not taking coverage and the benefit plans available are the same as above. However, households in this income category have premium assistance, so that they may not need to pay the entire amount of the premium. These individuals or households would be slightly more likely to pay this lower income-based contribution (between 8.0% and 9.5% of income depending on income as a % of FPL) to obtain coverage. This premium could be reduced further if the individual or household chose a Bronze level benefit with lower-level benefits than the Benchmark Silver plan and presumably lower premiums (remember that the subsidy is based on the Benchmark Silver premium).
For individuals or households with incomes between 100% and 250% of FPL, the cost of not choosing coverage is the same as stated in the prior two income scenarios. Households in the 100% to 250% of FPL income category will also receive the Premium Tax Subsidy described above, except that their contribution will only be between 2.0% and 8.0% of income. Persons in this income category will also receive additional benefits in the form of Cost-Share Reduction. For example, benefit plans for those with incomes between 100% to 150% of FPL will be based on the individual or household paying only about 6% of total health care costs (the members are not responsible for the other 94% of claims costs) for covered services. It is expected that most persons in the 100% to 250% income range who are eligible for coverage through the Individual Exchange will choose to purchase coverage.
Which Benefit Plan to Choose
Once an individual or household decides that they will purchase a plan on the Individual Exchange, this potential policyholder will need to decide which benefit plan to purchase. It is recommended that those with incomes between 100% to 250% purchase a Silver plan due to the Cost Share Reductions, as these reductions are only available on Silver plans for most eligible Americans.
In determining which policy to purchase, the prospective policyholder would ensure that the household members’ desired doctors, hospitals, and other providers were participating in any plan that might be chosen. The prospective policyholder would then compare the cost and benefits for the plans to determine which fits into the financial and risk tolerance goals of the household.
There are generally four levels of benefits (called metal levels) from which a prospective policyholder can choose: Bronze (60% AV), Silver (70% AV), Gold (80% AV), and Platinum (90% AV). The % AV is the actuarial value or percent of claims incurred for covered services for which the policy issuer (along with government payments) is responsible for paying. For a given issuer, Bronze plans are less expensive than Silver plans, which are less expensive than Gold plans, which are less expensive than Platinum plans. There may be substantial differences in premium between issuers, however, and Bronze plans for one issuer may actually be more expensive than Silver plans from another issuer. Reasons for rating differences between issuers include:
Due to the insurance company (issuer) uncertainties in determining claims costs and due to management pressures in some cases, some issuers will drop out of the market for financial reasons within a few years. However, policyholders will probably not lose coverage in these cases as the other issuers will probably take over these individuals from the failed issuer. Having said that, some prospective policyholders will probably choose familiar issuer names with which they are comfortable will be around and are financially stable.
Some individuals may look at the out-of-pocket maximum as a guide to determining the difference in plan value by metal level. Others may use deductibles as a guide. For example, if Issuer A has a Silver plan with a $6,400 out-of-pocket maximum and a Gold plan with a $5,000 out-of-pocket maximum, then a potential policyholder may deem the value of the Gold plan over the Silver plan to be ($6,400 – $5,000 =) $1,400. If the premium for the Gold plan is only $600 greater than that of the Silver plan, then the policyholder may decide that it is worth paying this additional money for the extra benefit. Others may use the deductible instead of the out-of-pocket in this comparison.
The premium rates will be valid until December 31, 2014. There will generally be rate increases on January 1, 2015, and then again for January 1, 2016. Since there is so much uncertainty, there may be wide swings in premium rates between the years as issuers understand the costs that their members are incurring more fully. The policyholders, however, may tend not to worry about future premium increases and base their decisions on the January 1, 2014 premium.
Please feel free to contact me at if you have any questions. Navigators in the Exchanges will be your best source of information, along with the website for the Exchange in your state.
By Jeff Adams, July 10, 2013
The American Academy of Actuaries recently released its White Paper on Financial Reporting Implications Under the Affordable Care Act. In case you missed it, a link to the article appears below:
This White Paper is a good summary of some of the financial reporting implications facing actuaries, especially in the first three years after the enactment of the Affordable Care Act (“ACA”). Actuaries have spent months trying to determine changes in risk and costs due to ACA in an effort to build them into premium rates. Now that the premium rates for small group and individual have been submitted, actuaries are now expending significantly more effort in analyzing changes in the financial statements due to ACA. Some items are much more difficult to estimate than others. For example, the Risk Adjuster estimate is not known for six months after the end of the calendar year, while the temporary reinsurance estimated accrual estimate could be reasonably obtained within a couple of months after the end of the calendar year. However, as the White Paper points out, there are scenarios where the estimation of the reinsurance recoveries may be inaccurate due to no fault of the actuary doing the estimation.
As the White Paper indicates, the additional accruals and possible increasing magnitude of existing accruals will cause significant volatility in financial statements for health care payors. Even the best actuaries and financial wizards will have difficulties in accurately estimating these accruals. Changes in accrual estimates may need to be booked promptly, possibly causing wide swings in underwriting results and problematic comparisons from one payor to another.
Issues with the Premium Tax Subsidy and the Cost-Sharing Reduction may also cause volatility in the financial statement. Persons whose income level changes may have its benefits or Premium Tax Subsidy changed. This could affect the financial statements. Premium Deficiency Reserves may also be required if significant losses are incurred by the issuer’s new products.
Please read the White Paper as it contains important information. If you have any comments or questions, you can contact the American Academy of Actuaries, or you can contact me, and I will try to assist you.
By Jeff Adams, May 10, 2013
My update on health care reform is that everything is going as expected, and that is not necessarily good. I attended a local Chamber of Commerce meeting on health care reform this morning, and confusion still reigns supreme. When the law was initially passed and people were complaining about the fact that the regulation had over 2,000 pages, I said, “That is necessary because health care is 17% of our economy and so complicated. Just wait, the government will need to send out over 100,000 pages of instructions before it goes live in 2014.” I am thinking that 100,000 pages was a gross understatement.
The Chamber meeting concentrated on the Individual and Small Group exchanges in New York State and the employer penalties for not offering affordable health care. The discussion on employer size is a good example of what has, and will, occur on many topics for a few years to come. Employers with over 50 employees are required to follow certain provisions regarding offering affordable health care. The Chamber of Commerce discussion on what constitutes an “employee” lasted 20 to 30 minutes. Many questions still remained at the end of the session. The problem is that the original law had a few pages on these requirements, necessarily not including many details due to the size of a document containing all such details for all such health care reform topics. Follow-up documents added more detail but could not possibly discuss all possible scenarios in all locations across the country. For example, one person asked if they could set up a temp service company specifically so that their company did not have to pay for health insurance for its employees who were not full-time all year. I am sure the drafters of the legislation did not think of that scenario or anything like it.
This is just one of many, many topics where details continue to flow from the government on how to implement health care reform, be it from the federal government or state government. All parties involved will continue to be frustrated through implementation and on into its first few years of operation as issues, ignored or not apparent currently, will need to be resolved after implementation.
Furthermore, health care reform does not adequately address two main concerns of our health care system. There are a couple of items in the Affordable Care Act (“ACA”) that have the potential to lower health care cost increases somewhat, but it will not be nearly enough—although better than the other alternative of repealing the law. Also, the uninsured population will decrease significantly initially due to the Premium Tax Subsidy, but, as stated in previous articles on this site, the details of ACA will dramatically erode this income-based subsidy over time, and people will choose to pay the penalty rather than keeping their health insurance.
So, this article has not said anything new, not a thing that we did not know before. I will end this article with something that one of today’s Chamber presenters said, although I paraphrase: Do not ignore health care reform! It will not go away anytime soon. With knowledge of the law, you can take advantage of its benefits and avoid some of its pitfalls. Many have chosen to ignore it and will regret it in a year or two.
By Jeff Adams, March 18, 2013
The Patient Protection and Affordable Care Act was passed in 2010, but much of the legislation will take effect on January 1, 2014. Much of the detail still needs to be ironed out quickly, and health care payors and providers are scrambling to decipher the latest releases from the Department of Health and Human Services (“HHS”). Once all the information is released and deciphered, the payors and providers must incorporate it into strategic and tactical plans for January 1, 2014, knowing that most of it needs to be in place well before then.
Much ado was made about the original legislation being 2,000 pages long. I said at the time that the law is rewriting one-sixths of our economy, so 2,000 pages is extremely small compared to what should be written. Before January 1, 2014, the federal government could release 100,000 pages of materials. I have no way of knowing exactly how many pages have been released, but I am sticking with my previous estimates. HHS seems to be trying very hard to get information from all parties involved before finalizing the pieces of the regulation. To their credit, they realize there is no way they can know all of the implications on all parties of 17% of our economy. All parties are invited to comment and, although no law will satisfy everyone,
HHS tries to be fair to the parties affected.
Actuaries working at the issuers (insurance companies) are scrambling to develop and submit rates in March, even though not all of the rules have been finalized by the federal government yet. Hospitals and other providers are also scrambling through the immense amount of work required, including developing Affordable Care Organizations and other provider organizations due to the new law, including different payment types than some providers are used to.
Health insurance Exchanges will start providing benefits as of January 1, 2014, for individuals and small groups, although open enrollment will be in fall 2013. Individuals will be able to purchase coverage through the Individual Exchange if affordable coverage is not available elsewhere for the individual. If an “income tax household” in which an individual resides has an income of less than 400% than the Federal Poverty Level (“FPL”), then they are able to purchase coverage from the Exchange for a cost of anywhere from 2% to 9.5% of household income, depending on the income level. The federal government will subsidize the difference between the individual contribution and the actual premium. FPL will be roughly $11,450 for the first person plus $4,000 for each additional household member. For example, a family of 4 has an FPL of $23,450 roughly. In addition, a tax household with an income of less than 250% of FPL will get additional benefits at no additional cost. Please see my previous article or contact me if you would like more detail.
The major reasons for the legislation are: 1) Decrease the number of uninsured. 2) Increase the quality of care. 3) Make health care more affordable for employers and the public. 4) Assist in controlling government spending on health care by being better able to control Medicare and Medicaid costs.
The number of uninsured will decrease substantially due to the premium subsidies for those with incomes less than 400% of the FPL, although there will still be a large number of uninsured. Increases in the quality of care and decreases in total cost for both the public and private sector are less of a certainty, however. The regulation creates Affordable Care Organizations (“ACO”) and the Patient-Centered Research Trust Institute (“PCRTI”) in an effort to increase quality of care while decreasing costs. ACOs are hospital and physician organizations that will receive part of its reimbursement based on the quality of care that it gives. PCRTI will develop a list of best practices and treatments for various conditions in an effort to increase effectiveness of treatment and eliminate the costs of poor health related to the performance of procedures that are not necessary. It remains to be seen if these will be effective at increasing quality of care and controlling costs.
As a reminder, many people, including me, believe that health care costs are one of the major issues in the US today. I can remember when health care was 11% of the US Gross Domestic Product and 13% of the Federal budget. It is now 17% of our economy and 24% of the Federal budget, and rising quality. For decades small employers have been dropping coverage because they cannot afford the large increases in premiums.
So what will happen as a result of health care reform? In the words of Max Klinger: “I don’t know. If I had all the answers, I’d run for God.” However, since this column is The World According to Jeff, I will take a stab at it.
1. Problems with deadlines will cause the Exchanges to have limited enrollment on January 1, 2014, and, therefore, limited effect on the number of uninsured. Nothing released by HHS indicates this, but I think some Exchanges will be allowed to have special enrollment periods during 2014 when Exchanges are fully functional.
2. The regulation will do little in the short term to control Medicaid and Medicare spending. As a result, these items will continue to be a budget issue through the next presidential election in 2016. Somewhat random cuts will be made to Medicaid and Medicare in the budget that will, directly or indirectly, reduce payments to providers and increase consumer payments through either higher copays or higher premiums. Effects of health care reform on cost may start to be felt in later years. The impact may be about 5% for services affected by the ACO quality payments. The impact of the research from the PCRTI is totally dependent on the type of research that is actually done by the Institute and what is done with this research.
3. 2014 premium rates for the Individual Exchange that will be submitted by the insurance companies to the state insurance departments for approval will be higher than the federal and state governments are hoping, setting up intense negotiations between the government entity responsible for approving the rates and the issuers.
4. The premium subsidy for the low-income will fade over time as premiums will increase faster than incomes and general CPI. Contributions for those with premium subsidies include the excess of any premium increase over the average increase in US income and general CPI. Insurers do not have a huge incentive to keep premiums down, but they do have an incentive to keep premiums high enough in this dynamic environment so as not to lose money. Again, an example of how the subsidy works appears in a prior article. In 2017 a reinsurance subsidy to the insurance companies goes away, causing them to increase premiums an additional 5% to 8% over 2014 rate levels—that is in addition to the normal trend.
5. Republicans and Democrats will fail to agree to any meaningful health care reform between now and 2017, instead sticking to party lines and doing little to control total health care expenditures. Health care will increase to over 18% of GDP by 2017, getting closer to the 20% threshold thought by many in the 1990s to be the magical level at which a major crisis in the US would be so serious it would require major, immediate reform. Not many still adhere to this, but there are many of us who consider this to be a crisis even at slightly over 17% of GDP.
6. Health care will be the main issue in the 2016 presidential campaign, with the worst possible scenario being a split Congress/Presidency again, leading to nothing meaningful being done.
OK, so that is The World According to Jeff. If you have any thoughts or questions, please feel free to email me.
By Jeff Adams, February 19, 2013
Articles posted on this website have often commented on the need for a reduction in health care costs, both for the financial integrity of the government and for affordability of private health care coverage. One provision in the Patient Protection and Affordable Care Act of 2010 (“ACA”) that has promise in helping to control health care costs is the provision establishing the Patient-Centered Outcomes Research Institute (“PCORI”). This institute is a private, non-profit corporation that performs research on comparative outcomes and clinical effectiveness of medical treatments in an effort to provide comparative information to assist patients, clinicians, purchasers, and policy-makers in making informed health care decisions.
PCORI has a 21-member Board of Governors with members from a cross-section of the health care system. Almost half of the Board members are physicians. Other members include consumer advocates, nurses and other providers, payor representatives such as from health insurers, and pharmaceutical, device, or diagnostic manufacturer representatives. ACA also requires Board members to include the Director of the Agency for Healthcare Research and Quality (“AHRQ”) and the Director of the National Institute of Health or their designees. Having such a small proportion of the Board from payors is designed to ensure that results are used to increase quality of care and efficiency and not used predominantly to minimize costs. Members of the Board of Governors and the Methodology Committee, described below, are appointed by the U.S. Government Accountability Office.
A 17-member Methodology Committee has also been established. The committee works to define methodological standards for research. The committee also develops and regularly updates a translation table to guide health care stakeholders towards the best methods for patient-centered outcomes research. More complete descriptions of the Board of Governors and Methodology Committee are available on the PCORI website, PCORI.org.
PCORI is funded by the PCORI Trust Fund. The Fund receives money on a per capita basis from payors based on Medicare, private insurers, and self-insured enrollment. The fee for payors is $1 per capita in 2013 and increasing each year through 2019 by the percent increase in National Health Expenditures. Federal government appropriations are also included in the Fund beginning with $10M in 2010 and increasing to $150M for 2012 through 2019.
Funds from the Trust Fund are used to provide grants for independent comparative studies of health care treatments. The PCORI website indicated on February 19, 2013, that $40.7M in grants had been provided in the past three years. These grants have been given for studies such as a Massachusetts study analyzing the benefits of a collaboration of a hospital and a Patient-Centered Medical Home within an Accountable Care Organization. Other studies analyze treatments for diabetes and depression.
The Office of Communication and Knowledge Transfer of AHRQ is required to communicate the results of the studies sponsored by PCORI broadly. PCORI cannot mandate reimbursement or benefits based on the information received from the studies. Medicare also cannot determine payments or benefits based solely on these studies. Instead, these studies are designed to be just another tool that will be available for patients, clinicians, purchasers, and policy-makers to help determine the best treatment plans.
Like many elements of ACA, the actual impact of PCORI will not be known for a few years. It will take years to complete the few studies already receiving funded by PCORI grants. Future grants will continue to provide information that can be used to help stakeholders determine the most appropriate treatment protocol in order to increase quality of care and efficiency. Like other proposals to improve our health care delivery system, this is not a Silver Bullet, just another tool to help in getting us where we would like to go in modifying our health care system. Depending on its effectiveness, a very rough guess is that PCORI could save 5% to 15% in a mature state.
By Jeff Adams
As part of the ACA, health insurance exchanges will offer health policies to individuals. There will be subsidies available to these individuals if their household income is less than 400% of the Federal Poverty Level (“FPL”) and they do not qualify for health care coverage through another source. Persons will either need to have some form of health care coverage (employer-based, government, individual, etc.) or pay a penalty. The purpose of this narrative is to describe the government premium subsidy for individuals with incomes less than 400% of FPL.
Persons with household income between 100% and 400% of FPL eligible for coverage through the Exchange may get a subsidy on premium payment to coverage through their regional exchange. In order to get this subsidy, these persons must not be eligible for coverage through any other source (employer-based, government coverage, coverage through a family member, etc.)
The FPL is set by the federal government and is based on the number of persons in the household. There is an FPL for the continental United States, an FPL for Alaska, and an FPL for Hawaii. For example, in 2014, the FPL for states other than Alaska and Hawaii may be $11,450 for the first individual and $4,000 for each additional household member. That would mean the FPL for a three-person household in 2014 would be $19,450 ($11,450 + 2 x $4,000). A three-person household that submits an income tax filing totaling $58,350 would have Income as a Percent of FPL of 300% ($58,350 / $19,450 x 100%).
Once income as a % of FPL has been calculated, the following table will be used to determine the % of the household income that the household will have to pay for the Benchmark plan set of benefits, which will be described later:
Income as % of FPL | Contribution as % of Income |
---|---|
100% | 2.0% |
133% | 3.0% |
150% | 4.0% |
200% | 6.3% |
250% | 8.0% |
300% | 9.5% |
400% | 9.5% |
As an example, the three-person household would be able to purchase a Benchmark set of benefits in 2014 for $5,543.25 ($58,350 times 9.5%) since the household income is 300% of FPL. If the income as % of FPL does not appear in the table above, then the contribution % would be a linear interpolation of the values in the table (275% would result in contributions as a % of income of 8.75%).
The Benchmark set of benefits to which a policyholder would be entitled for the contribution described above would vary by exchange but would be the second least expensive Silver plan offered in the appropriate regional exchange. The ACA dictates that a Silver plan must pay for approximately 70% of eligible expenses. Eligible expenses are defined by the Federal government and are called Essential Health Benefits. A sample of what a Silver plan might look like is a $3,000 deductible, 30% policyholder copay, and a $6,250 out-of-pocket maximum.
Additionally, households eligible for the subsidy whose income are less than 250% of FPL are entitled to benefit plans richer than the Benchmark plan described above. Specifically, the regulation describes these increases through the use of the Actuarial Value table below:
Minimum | Maximum | Actuarial Value |
---|---|---|
100% | 149.90% | 94% |
150% | 199.90% | 87% |
200% | 249.90% | 73% |
250% | 400% | 70% |
As an example, a household with income at 150% of FPL would be entitled to a benefit plan that paid approximately 94% of eligible charges if they were to contribute 4.0% of their household income.
After 2014 and through 2018, policyholders will be responsible for the contributions calculated via the formula above but will also be responsible for the difference between the % increase in premiums for the Benchmark plan for each of those years and the % increase in a national income index for that particular year. Thus, the policyholder will have to pay additional amounts if health care costs increase more than national average incomes in 2015 through 2018. Similarly, after 2018 policyholders will need to pay any increases in health care costs greater than the general United States Consumer Price Index increases. These possible additional policyholder contributions give added importance to implementing controls to restrain out-of-control health care cost increases in future years.
A publicly available subsidy calculator has been published by the Kaiser Foundation and can be found at:
Adams Actuarial LLC also has a more detailed subsidy calculator. If you have any questions or comments, please feel to contact Adams Actuarial LLC.
(585) 412-6895 | 165 Saxton Lane, Canandaigua, NY 14424, USA | Email
© 2021 Adams Actuarial LLC. All Rights Reserved. Web Design by Web.com